Harper's Weekly/Abusing the Plaintiff's Attorney
ABUSING THE PLAINTIFF'S ATTORNEY.
If Senator Morton really feels the profound
contempt for experience which he
expresses, the country has been greatly
mistaken in supposing him to be a sagacious
statesman. Senator Schurz makes a
masterly exposition of the consequences that
have always followed inflation under the
circumstances in which this country is now
placed. He shows further the principles
which have produced and must always
produce this result. He refutes statements
based upon a superficial resemblance in the
situation of different countries, and presents
the actual facts of their condition. He exposes
relentlessly the sophistries about the
currency with which the air fairly hums,
and declares that in his opinion the popular
feeling is hostile to inflation. And, in reply,
Mr. Morton — for he really compels us to say
so — resorts to tactics to which he has
condescended before, and merely abuses the
plaintiff's attorney. He said that he could
not attempt to answer off-hand a carefully
prepared speech — which was a very good
reason for not speaking off-hand. But he
went on to say that the cheapest of political
learning was that obtained from cramming;
that he had known people to cram for the
stump upon three or four old speeches; that
many things were true in Europe that were
not true here; that Mr. Schurz was ignorant
of the country in which he lived, but was
what is called in France a political littérateur;
that he was not the only man who had
read all the books; that he talked about
China, a country that was finished and walled
up a thousand years ago, and that this
country would soon be finished also if his
doctrines should prevail.
The object of this outburst is plain. Mr. Morton was conscious that the facts and arguments of Mr. Schurz's speech had impressed the Senate, and would impress the country. He could not answer the arguments nor deny the facts, but he might try to break their force by ridiculing their author and appealing to prejudices. Mr. Schurz was German born, and he was a student, and he had led a schism in the Republican party; so Mr. Morton “went for him” as a professor and a pedant, a littérateur and a doctrinaire, who had read books, but knew nothing of practical affairs, and who, upon the whole, was rather an impudent fellow to lecture the American Senate so loftily. It was the only course left to Mr. Morton, if, having nothing to say, as he stated, he was still resolved to speak.
But, as a statesman and a practical man he must be aware that he seriously weakens his influence and his standing among sensible men by so contemptuously flouting experience and the result of the wisest observation and thought. If, as he says, he has read all the books, he knows that, so far as the fundamental facts are concerned, there is no essential difference between the situation of this country and that of all other commercial and manufacturing countries with an irredeemable currency. From the same sources, also, he must know that no argument for inflation has been advanced in Congress which has not been more powerfully urged in Parliament and elsewhere, and utterly refuted by the most trained practical sagacity. Again, while denouncing theorists, he knows, of course, “from the books” that the theorist Adam Smith has influenced the prosperity of England more than any other man, and that it was the Manchester theorists who converted that eminent practical statesman, Sir Robert Peel, and persuaded him to the best act of his public career. The world is ruled by thinkers, who are always denounced as theorists, and legislation is really practical and beneficial only so far as it conforms to the conclusions of thought and observation. The point upon which Mr. Morton and the inflationists constantly insist, but which, as yet, they have failed to prove, is the essential difference in the present financial situation of this country from similar situations in all other countries.
This work is in the public domain in the United States because it was published before January 1, 1929.
This work may be in the public domain in countries and areas with longer native copyright terms that apply the rule of the shorter term to foreign works.
Public domainPublic domainfalsefalse