Page:A History of Banking in the United States.djvu/97

From Wikisource
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This page has been proofread, but needs to be validated.
INFLATION ON THE ATLANTIC COAST.
75

upon bank credit, the banks being very liberal. Superficial observers have blamed them for too free loans, over-issues, and over-trading. These charges were highly unjust. They were only to be blamed for too great loans to some individuals, and for curtailing their loans in order to invest in government securities. He expected the national bank to emancipate men from slavish dependence upon the local banks for loans.[1]

One of the current notions of the time, which always recurs under similar circumstances, was that it was the specie which had advanced and not the paper which had depreciated; and another was that by the advance of civilization and its arts, paper had superseded specie as money. These notions were very wide-spread in England at the time, under the suspension of specie payments by the Bank of England, and they can be traced in the writings of the American pamphleteers. Of the former notion, Raguet said that it was beginning to be abandoned in 1816.[2] Both these doctrines were most ably expounded by Dr. Bollmann in his "Plan of Money Concerns." In this "Plan" he maintained that the general government ought to agree to pay the interest of the public debt in coin, and that the notes of the national bank ought to be payable on demand in six per cent. stock at par, or in specie at the option of the institution. The national bank ought to have no branches, but to be the bank of the banks. The notes of all the banks in any one State should be made convertible on demand in the notes of one designated central bank, and the notes of these chief State banks ought to be redeemable in notes of the national bank. There should be no notes of the national bank under $5, and said notes should be made legal tender. The charter of the Bank of the United States was published in time for him to notice it in a postcript. He was extremely displeased with it. "A volume might be written on this ill-judged scheme."

Carey pronounced Dr. Boilmann's plan a magnificent one, and said: "It would be a sovereign remedy for all the financial difticulties of the country."[3] That plan seems to have influenced the minds of the persons who invented the Pennsylvania "relief" system of 1841.[4]

An anonymous writer of 1819[5] ridicules the notion of a lack of circulating medium urged in favor of banks of circulation. "Everyone ought to, and will, receive of the circulating medium that quantity which he is entitled to by his property or industry, unless it is diverted from its natural channels by the knavery of banking Legislatures, which is the case in this country." He regarded note-issuers as robbers.

Dallas issued a circular July 22, 1816, in which he called upon the banks, especially those of the Middle States, to meet the Treasury in an effort to put the resolution of April 29th into effect. He proposed that the banks should agree to the publication by the Secretary of a notice that he would not receive, after October 1st, any notes of any bank which did not pay its notes for five dollars or less in specie, and that, after February 20, 1817, the

  1. Essays, 161.
  2. Report on the Distress, 1820.
  3. Letters to the Directors of the Banks, 1816.
  4. See page 344.
  5. Cause and Cure of Hard Times, 12.